Abstract
We submit that the central managerial messages of transaction cost economics (TCE) have been lost or misconstrued in academic debates that miss the underpinning logic of the theory. Critiques of TCE are often based on narrow and selective interpretations, indeed caricatures. Our goal is to set the record straight by examining TCE’s fundamentally constructive aims, logic, and its applicability in the classroom. Looks can be deceiving: While TCE candidly acknowledges that bad things sometimes happen, the main message is not only constructive and positive, but also consistent with a stakeholder theory of management. Indeed, we maintain that TCE can be applied as a constructive stakeholder theory.
REFERENCES
- 1988. The firm is dead; long live the firm: A review of Oliver E. Williamson’s The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Journal of Economic Literature, 26: 65–79. Google Scholar
- 2007. Contract design as a firm capability: An integration of learning and transaction cost perspectives. Academy of Management Review, 32: 1060–1077.Link , Google Scholar
- 1999. Contractual commitments, bargaining power, and governance inseparability: Incorporating history into transaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review, 24: 49–63.Link , Google Scholar
- 1999. A team production theory of corporate law. Virginia Law Review, 85: 247–328. Google Scholar
- 1995. Beyond rhetoric and realism in economics: Towards a reformulation of economic methodology. London: Routledge. Google Scholar
- 2006. The impact of empirical tests of transaction cost economics on the debate on the nature of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 27: 461–476. Google Scholar
- 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica, 4: 386–405. Google Scholar
- 1992. A behavioral theory of the firm (2nd ed.). Englewood Cliffs, CA: Prentice-Hall. Google Scholar
- 1995. The stakeholder theory of the corporation: Concepts, evidence, and implications. Academy of Management Review, 20: 65–91.Link , Google Scholar
- 1973. Writing without teachers. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Google Scholar
- 2005. Economics language and assumptions: How theories can become self-fulfilling. Academy of Management Review, 30: 8–24.Link , Google Scholar
- 2010. Critiques of transaction cost economics: An overview. In P. G. Klein, & M. E. Sykuta (Eds.), The Elgar companion to transaction cost economics: 263–272. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Google Scholar
- 2010. Stakeholder theory: The state of the art. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar
- 2004. Stakeholder theory and “The Corporate Objective Revisited.” Organization Science, 15: 364–369. Google Scholar
- 2005. Bad management theories are destroying good management practices. Academy of Management Learning & Education, 4: 75–91.Link , Google Scholar
- 1996. Bad for practice: A critique of the transaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review, 21: 13–47.Link , Google Scholar
- 2010. Money for nothing: How the failure of corporate boards is ruining American business and costing us trillions. New York: Free Press. Google Scholar
- 2002. Business education’s role in the crisis of corporate confidence. Academy of Management Learning & Education, 16: 142–144.Abstract , Google Scholar
- 1976. Regulation and administered contracts. The Bell Journal of Economics, 7: 426–448. Google Scholar
- 1985. Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91: 481–510. Google Scholar
- 1986. The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration. Journal of Political Economy, 94: 691–719. Google Scholar
- 1988. Ownership of the firm. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 4: 267–304. Google Scholar
- 1997. The proper scope of government: Theory and an application to prisons. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112: 1127–1161. Google Scholar
- 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305–360. Google Scholar
- 1984. An empirical investigation of some antecedents of opportunism in a marketing channel. Journal of Marketing Research, 21: 278–289. Google Scholar
- 2008. Are U.S. CEOs overpaid? The Academy of Management Perspectives, 22: 5–20.Link , Google Scholar
- 2010. Two strategies for inductive reasoning in organizational research. Academy of Management Review, 35: 315–333.Link , Google Scholar
- 2012. Creating and capturing value in public-private ties: A private actor’s perspective. Academy of Management Review, 37: 272–299.Link , Google Scholar
- 1978. Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process. The Journal of Law & Economics, 21: 297–326. Google Scholar
- 2012. Who is in charge? A property rights perspective on stakeholder governance. Strategic Organization, 10: 304–315. Google Scholar
- 2002. Addressing the crisis in confidence in corporations: Root causes, victims, and strategies for reform. The Academy of Management Executive, 16: 139–141.Abstract , Google Scholar
- 1996. Explaining firm capital structure: The role of agency theory vs. transaction cost economics. Strategic Management Journal, 17: 713–728. Google Scholar
- 1996. A country is not a company. Harvard Business Review, 74(1): 40–51. Google Scholar
- Lakatos I.Musgrave A. (Eds.). 1970. Criticism and the growth of knowledge. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar
- 1992. The resource-based view within the conversation of strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 13: 363–380. Google Scholar
- 1994. A primer on decision making: How decisions happen. New York: Free Press. Google Scholar
- 2004. Learning to contract: Evidence from the personal computer industry. Organization Science, 15: 394–410. Google Scholar
- 1882. A system of logic, ratiocinative and inductive, being a connected view of the principles of evidence, and the methods of scientific investigation (8th ed.). New York: Harper & Brothers. Google Scholar
- 2006. Images of organization (Updated ed.). London: Sage Publications. Google Scholar
- 1998. Social capital, intellectual capital, and the organizational advantage. Academy of Management Review, 23: 242–266.Link , Google Scholar
- 1982. An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. Google Scholar
- 2012. Exploring the problem-finding and problem-solving approach for designing organizations. Academy of Management Perspectives, 26: 52–72.Link , Google Scholar
- 2004. A knowledge-based theory of the firm—The problem-solving perspective. Organization Science, 15: 617–632. Google Scholar
- 1977. Review of markets and hierarchies. Administrative Science Quarterly, 22: 541–544. Google Scholar
- 2005. Why do bad management theories persist? A comment on Ghoshal. Academy of Management Learning & Education, 4: 96–100.Link , Google Scholar
- 2006. Hard facts, dangerous half-truths & total nonsense. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. Google Scholar
- 1964. Strong inference. Science, 146: 347–353. Google Scholar
- 1997. Transaction cost analysis: Past, present, and future applications. Journal of Marketing, 61: 30–54. Google Scholar
- 2005. Organizational boundaries and theories of organization. Organization Science, 16: 491–508. Google Scholar
- 1960. The strategy of conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Google Scholar
- 2010. A tribute to Oliver Williamson: Antitrust economics. California Management Review, 52: 138–146. Google Scholar
- 1990. Economics and sociology: Redefining their boundaries. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Google Scholar
- 1997. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 18: 509–533. Google Scholar
- 2003. The uses of argument (Updated ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar
- 1980. The scientific image. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Google Scholar
- 1984. A transaction cost approach to make-or-buy decisions. Administrative Science Quarterly, 29: 373–391. Google Scholar
- 2008. CEO compensation and the responsibilities of the business scholar to society. Academy of Management Perspectives, 22: 26–33.Link , Google Scholar
- 2010. Simon says, “expand the definition of bounded rationality in management research.” Paper presented at the 2010 Atlanta Competitive Advantage Conference. Atlanta, GA. Google Scholar
- 1988. The industrial organization of Congress; or, why legislatures, like firms, are not organized as markets. Journal of Political Economy, 96: 132–163. Google Scholar
- 2007. The limitations of buyer-option contracts in solving the holdup problem. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 23: 127–140. Google Scholar
- 1975. Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press. Google Scholar
- 1983. Credible commitments: Using hostages to support exchange. The American Economic Review, 73: 519–540. Google Scholar
- 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press. Google Scholar
- 1988. Corporate finance and corporate governance. The Journal of Finance, 43: 567–591. Google Scholar
- 1991. Strategizing, economizing, and economic organization. Strategic Management Journal, 12: 75–94. Google Scholar
- 1993. Opportunism and its critics. Managerial and Decision Economics, 14: 97–107. Google Scholar
- 1996a. Economic organization: The case for candor. Academy of Management Review, 21: 48–57.Link , Google Scholar
- 1996b. The mechanisms of governance. New York: Oxford University Press. Google Scholar
- 1996c. Transaction cost economics and the Carnegie connection. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 31: 149–155. Google Scholar
- 1999a. Public and private bureaucracies: A transaction cost economics perspective. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 15: 306–342. Google Scholar
- 1999b. Strategy research: Governance and competence perspectives. Strategic Management Journal, 20: 1087–1108. Google Scholar
- 2000. The new institutional economics: Taking stock, looking ahead. Journal of Economic Literature, 38: 595–613. Google Scholar
- 2002. The merger guidelines of the U.S. Department of Justice: In perspective. Talk given at the 20th anniversary of the adoption of the 1982 Merger Guidelines, June 20, 2002, The Anti-trust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice (full text available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/hmerger/11257.htm). Google Scholar
- 2008. Corporate boards of directors: In principle and in practice. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 24: 247–272. Google Scholar
- 2010. Transaction cost economics: The natural progression. Journal of Retailing, 86: 215–226. Google Scholar
- 1993. From transaction cost to transactional value analysis: Implications for the study of interorganizational strategies. Journal of Management Studies, 30: 131–145. Google Scholar